Sectoral interaction and transformation of a predominantly agrarian aconomy : A discourse in the light of the classical political economy frameworks

Part of : Αρχείον οικονομικής ιστορίας ; Vol.XXVII, No.2, 2015, pages 5-18

Issue:
Pages:
5-18
Author:
Abstract:
This article is concerned with the interactions between the agricultural and non-agricultural sectors of an economy as conceived in the classical political economy frameworks in the context of the process of economic development. It is argued that while Quesnay emphasizes agriculture in producing economic surplus and, in contrast, Adam Smith stresses industry, both of them have recognized the importance of interactions or inter-linkages between these two sectors in a growing economy. Agricultural growth strengthens domestic market and thus creates demand for manufactured goods and, in turn, the industrial class will spend more on agricultural produce (the Physiocrats). On the other hand, for higher growth through higher productivity as well as efficiency, industry would employ the strategy of division of labour through extensive subdivisions in the production system (Adam Smith). And this will lead to expansion in industrial employment opportunity for the labour abundant in the agricultural sector. The paper then discusses transformation of a predominantly agrarian economy in the light of the theories of Ricardo and Marx. The Ricardian system even helps us understand today’s situation where industrial capital is entering into agriculture through contract farming and agro-processing business. The Marxian analysis saw the proletarianization of the peasantry with the rise of capitalism. According to Marx, destruction of rural domestic industry can provide the internal market which the capitalist mode of production requires.
Subject:
Subject (LC):
Keywords:
classical political economy, agriculture/non-agriculture interactions, economic development
Notes:
JEL Classification: B12, Q10, O10, O20
References (1):
  1. Barkai, H. (1959): “Ricardo on Factor Prices and Income Distribution in a Growing Economy”, Economica, Vol. 26, No. 103, pp. 240-250.Bharadwaj, Krishna (1987). “Analytics of Agriculture-Industry Relation”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 22, No. 19-21, pp. 15-20.Dobb, Maurice (1973). Theories of Value and Distribution since Adam Smith. Ideology and Economic Theory, Cambridge. Cambridge University Press (republished in India in 1979 by Vikas Publishing House Pvt Ltd, New Delhi).Edelberg, Victor (1933). “The Ricardian Theory of Profits”, Economica, No.39 (old series), pp. 51-74.Eltis, Walter (1988). “The Role of Industry in Economic Development. The Contrasting Theories of Francois Quesnay and Adam Smith”. In The Balancebetween Industry and Agriculture in Economic Development, Vol. 1, Part II, Basic Issues, pp. 175-197, ed. Kenneth J. Arrow. New York. St. Martin’s Press (in association with the International Economic Association).Fellner, William (1960). Emergence and Content of Modern Economic Analysis; New York. McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc.; and Tokyo. Kōgakusha Company, Ltd.Gide, Charles and Charles Rist (1915). A History of Economic Doctrines. From the Time of the Physiocrats to the Present Day. UK. D.C. Heath and Company.Harriss, Barbara (1987). “Regional Growth Linkages from Agriculture and Resource Flows in Non-farm Economy”. Economic and Political Weekly 22 (1 & 2), pp. 31-46.Hollander, S. (1973). “Ricardo’s Analysis of the Profit Rate, 1813-15”; Economica, Vol. 40, No. 159, pp. 260-282.Johnson, Jerah (1966). “The Role of Spending in Physiocratic Theory”, TheQuarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 80, No. 4, pp. 616-632.Khan, Amir Ullah (2004). “Growth and the Poor Farmer. Why is It So Important to Reform Agriculture?” In Bibek Debroy and Amir Ullah Khan (eds.), Integrating the Rural Poor into Markets, pp. 91-98; New Delhi. Academic Foundation (in association with International Development Enterprises, India, and India Development Foundation).Kurz, Heinz D. (2012). “Two Critics of Marginalist Theory. Piero Sraffa and John Maynard Keynes,” Investigación Económica, Vol. 71, No. 280, pp. 23-54.Lewis, W.A. (1954). “Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour,” The Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 22, No. 2, pp. 139-191.Marx, Karl (1954). Capital, (Vol. 1). Moscow. Progress Publishers.Meek, Ronald L. (1962). The Economics of Physiocracy. Essays and Translations. London. George Allen & Unwin Ltd. (Ruskin House).Pasinetti, Luigi L. (1962). “Rate of Profit and Income Distribution in Relation to the Rate of Economic Growth,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 29, No. 4, pp. 267-279.Pressman, Steven (1999). Fifty Great Economists, London and New York. Routledge.Ranis, G. and J. Fei (1961). “A Theory of Economic Development”, American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4, pp. 533-565.Roncaglia, Alessandro (1983). “Piero Sraffa and the Reconstruction of PoliticalEconomy,” BNL Quarterly Review, Vol. 36, No. 147, pp. 337-51.Singh, Gurdev and S.R. Asokan (2005). “Contract Farming in India.” In India’sAgricultural Challenges. Reflections on Policy, Technology and Other Issues, ed., Ramesh Chand, pp. 79-103, New Delhi. Centre for Trade and Development (CENTAD).Smith, Adam (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth ofNations. London. Methuen and Co., Ltd.Vygodsky, S. (1966). Capitalist Economy; Moscow. Progress Publisher.